Kitabı oku: «Claves del derecho de redes empresariales», sayfa 3

Yazı tipi:

In all these cases we find conducts which are far from competition by efficiency. The network head, either alone or in connexion with other network members, undertakes interference, obstruction or predatory practices affecting other members. These conducts infringe good faith and fair dealing — contractual and market ones — as well as loyalty principles.

Interference with contractual relations, with reasonable expectations or business relations, with prospective economic advantages, and the induction refusal to deal are some groups of these kind of typical network bad practices.

Such practices deprive network members of the possibility to obtain the benefits they can reasonably expect from their investments and limit their expectations in the market.

The prohibition of encroachment may be grounded in the principles of loyalty, fair trade or good faith, depending on the different legal systems. Its acceptance varies from the British quasi negation to the German or Nordic firm defence.

A legal framework for networks must deal with these three questions: the protection of investments and reasonable expectations of network members, the recognition of directory’s coordination power, and the limits between legitimate competition and illegitimate interference.

The limits on the exercise of coordination by the network directory due to antitrust rules are, however, less relevant than it seems at first sight.

In cases involving the network head — acting in its own benefit or giving advantage to another member of the network — customer network reallocation comes from a discretionary decision of the network head and not from competition by efficiency.

Interference or encroachment are usually directed against highly efficient distributors for reasons clearly unrelated to competition policy such as preventing that a given member of the network gains too much internal weight or preventing the creation of autonomous power centres within the network that concede a greater bargaining power to its members.

A hypothetical intra-brand increased competition after the encroachment or interference does not justify the potential harm to the interests of one network member not covered by the prosecution of the shared interest when the conduct does not increase the inter-brand competition.

The exercise of coordination power to prevent encroachment or tortious interference shall not affect in any way inter-brand competition, since in these cases there is a cannibalization of customers belonging to the network and not an injection of new customers for the network.

The exercise of coordination power by network directory in cases of internal predatory practices between members also avoids the removal of members of the network and therefore the reduction of the number of competitors in the market keeping the competitive strength of the network. It has therefore a pro-competitive nature.

IV. NETWORK - THIRD PROBLEMS

Network members have business relationships with other businessmen and costumers — consumers or not —. A network may also be integrated in another — for example a credit cooperative member of a second degree cooperative integrated in a horizontal group part of a strategic alliance to have access to South American markets —.

Network members have individual relationships but these affect in many cases all network members or some of them —in the case the network head —.

Contractual and organizational regulations give not a satisfactory answer to questions like when the network relationship shall be recognized in business member/third relations, and to what extension.

This paper deals with two of these important problems: direct action and bankruptcy.

a. Direct action

One of the main problems to solve in network-thirds relationships is the possibility to act against a network member for the acts or omissions of another. In both organizational and contractual networks, separate legal personality of the consortium, horizontal group, EIG or cooperative or contractual parties and privy doctrine ensure the general refusal to this possibility. The described result can be obtained as a general remedy in some branches of Law only, such as antitrust law, in which the economic reality prevails over legal formality as a characteristic element, or by using some exceptional remedies such as the piercing the veil doctrine. The induction to law or contract infringement as an unfair competition act may also be used to reach this goal and the consumer protection rules as liability for defective products may also help.

This group of rules and court doctrines — with variable relevance in the Law of the EU member states, because they are outside of the harmonized area — are not enough to rule in an efficient form the relationships between third and network.

The doctrine of contracts connexion13 and the revision of privy doctrine try to solve these problems but there is no general acceptation of their conclusions.

A network legal framework explains more accurately the cases in which a direct action shall be accepted, generally against the network head but also against another network member. Discussion over liability in groups of companies may help us to understand these problems and to find solutions. Execution of network head’s instructions or diligent application of its directives shall be enough justification to admit the direct liability of the network head when the conduct of the member causes damage.

b. Bankruptcy in networks

The network members or the network head may be declared in bankruptcy. The more important effects on the network are produced in the second case. The two main questions in this field are the effects of bankruptcy without liquidation and with continuity of the activity in network contracts, being these long term contracts with successive execution needed to maintain the bankrupted company activity, and the network members possibility to finance, take participation or purchase the network head before or during the bankruptcy procedure14.

The bankruptcy of the network head produces severe consequences on the members in terms of goodwill, continuity of its own business, and leadership of the network, but these damages are not illicit and in general the members are not or very limited creditors of the network head. The bankruptcy procedure focusing on creditors tuition ignores the network members problematic and does not provide for them any special remedy or particular position in the bankruptcy procedure.

These are cases where the insolvent debtor’s business is susceptible to be restructured, in which economically linked firms are competitive in the market and the losses are caused by reasons not affecting the network members such as a corporate cost structure that does not reflect income from the typical activity, by an excessive reliance on external financing, by speculative investments, by the implementation of new production or research lines or foreign development activity undertaken by the insolvent debtor, by inadequate risk management, by internal business of the debtor bankrupt, or simply by extraordinary and extravagant personal expenses incurred by the debtor bankrupt.

As Bankruptcy Law is not a harmonized field in Europe, national legal systems present important differences. Talking from the Spanish experience it will be necessary that the bankruptcy administration and the Judge may identify in a simple and clear way which are the network companies. In some cases, such as franchising this may be relative easy but in other ones like outsourcing it may be more difficult.

Related companies present in procedure shall also be heard by the judge before he or she decides about the total or partial termination or suspension of business or about the closure of offices, facilities or production units if they are essential for the development of the economic activity on which the network depends like, for example, the research and development department in the case of networks based on software licenses or contracts for technology transfer.

Possible improvements of the settlement deal with two issues: the proposition of a convention and the order of deliberation of a proposed convention in the Assembly of creditors, if there is a plurality of proposals.

It seems appropriate to give preference in the discussion to the proposals of network members, at least when they are supported by a significant percentage of creditors, giving them the possibility to be discussed immediately after the rejection of the proposal by the debtor bankrupt.

Regarding the liquidation, it seems appropriate to recognize an independent right to network members to make comments or propose modifications to the settlement plan presented by the bankruptcy administration to the court, similar to the one held by workers.

The network members should be heard by the judge, just like workers of the bankrupt debtor’s business are, in the case of the joint sale of the company or the production units whose activities have a direct connection with the network activity.

In case of a separate auction for the rights and assets belonging to the active mass there could be a right of first refusal with respect to the bankrupt debtor’s assets which are essentials to the efficient pursuit of the activity or to maintain the competitiveness of the network.

The special interdependence of networks members justifies in these cases a priority right to take the control of the other member specially if it is the network head, before or during the procedure. For creditors this has the advantage of increasing the bankrupt solvability, and it ensures the continuity of the network activity — which in many cases it is the best way to be paid —. For the members this also implies the continuity of their own business and, if it is the case, the continuity of network leadership, in this case collective.

An efficient legal network framework should deal with these questions and include the same or similar solutions.

V. NETWORK AND PUBLIC INTEREST PROBLEMS

Networks are also relevant from the point of view of public interest. Networks often produce external benefits, from cultural to ecological, as a consequence of its interdependent activity. But we will now focus only on the interest in maintaining a workable competition for the benefit of the market and all its participants, mainly the consumers.

On this field there are many network issues in relation with networks mergers15, networks presence in the market in comparison to independent sellers or buyers, abusive practices in networks with impact on the market, and grounds of exemption (Block exemptions and ancillary restraints doctrine16).

We will discuss two of these questions, namely the abuse of dependence and the possibility to extend the application of ancillary restraints doctrine in the field of networks.

a. Abuse of dependence in networks

Business relationships in networks are different than hierarchy or market relations as a consequence of the interdependence of its members. This interdependence can be transformed in some cases in dependence understood as the absence of an equivalent alternative for one of the parties. This includes the absolute absence or the existence of a not reasonable alternative in economic terms, — for example, a producer who sells 100% of its production to a big surface and has done specific investments which cannot be amortized and who cannot place its production in the market —, or a member of a wine second degree cooperative who produces bottled wine when as a consequence of strategic alliances (network/network connexion) with a foreign importer the ownership of the successful trademarks belongs to the second degree cooperative. In these cases the cost to leave the second degree cooperative is not reasonable in economic terms.

The abuse of dependence is not ruled in a uniform way neither in European Law nor in the different laws of the member states. European Courts created the doctrine of relative abuse to deal with cases in which the abuse implies a negative effect over the competition in the market following the German and French legal conceptions. In Spain the abuse of dependence is an unfair competition conduct — art. 16.2 LCD17 — that may have antitrust relevance through article 3 LDC18 if it affects the public interest to maintain a workable competition in the market. Opposite to this line of regulation, Italy regulates the abuse of dependence in civil law as a private matter.

The abuse of dependence has an impact in the formation of the contractual agreement, as an unfair competition conduct, and it may lead to a risk for the workable competition in the market in some cases19. A legal network framework shall deal with all these three aspects and not consider them as alternatives. It shall regulate all of them knowing that the relevant level of dependence in each case may not be the same.

b. Ancillary Restraints doctrine and networks

Exemptions to the application of the prohibition of agreements and practices restrictive of competition in European Law are organized in four different ways. Ancillary restraints doctrine, block exemptions, 101.3 Treaty criteria and de minimis rule. This last one is grounded in the opportunity principle that rules the action of the administration but in fact it has an influence on the private application of competition law that is not clearly justified.

The criteria of 101.3 are grounded in an efficient competition balance recognizing competition as a means to obtain more, better and cheaper goods or services for more customers — quantitatively and geographically extended — and not as a goal in itself and its application produces the compensation of restriction of competition with these goals that are obtained through anticompetitive behaviour with the three limits it establishes. These rules are able to be applied in all kind of cases but if we observe the block exemption regulations we may conclude that in most cases they exempt, in both vertical and horizontal cases, stable business cooperation relationships that can be identified as cases of business networks.

Accessory restraints doctrine, grounded in the idea that a necessary little evil shall not deprive us of a good, has also been applied until now only to a case — distribution and services franchising — that may be described as a vertical business network.

It is quite difficult to modify a block exemption, as shows the actual negotiation about the substitution of the vertical restrictions block exemption. On the contrary, the evolution of a judicial doctrine may be easier to obtain since it suffices to convince a small group of persons among the best jurists in Europe, who act according to technical and justice considerations instead of political ones.

In the case of vertical restraints, the risk for competition is generally low, with the exception of exclusionary effects or market sharing.

We shall keep in mind that business networks — vertical and horizontal — are considered, both in national and community systems, as highly beneficial to the economy in general — efficiencies’ exponential growth — and to the modernization — today just the survival — of SMEs, which allow a reasonable benefits allocation among its members and consumers.

Distribution networks in particular have been seen as positive in general terms on both sides of the Atlantic although the European Court of Justice denies the application of the rule of reason.

The application of the ancillary restraints doctrine to horizontal business networks would be more problematic but the ground of the doctrine is general and it would be applicable also to these cases.

In order to explore this possibility, we shall determine whether the intra-brand restrictions derived from the exercise of directive power and control which are inherent in networks’ governance are justified from the perspective of their incidental nature regarding a legitimate and desirable result as the existence of enterprise networks.

In European Competition Law the concept of ancillary restraints covers any alleged restriction of competition which is directly related to conducting a major not restrictive operation, in our case the creation of a network contract, and which is objectively necessary and proportionate.

In the case of distribution networks efficient territorial organization of the network members, for example, is directly related to network efficiency and indissolubly linked to it20.

Following with the example, an objective and abstract analysis of the need for the territorial organization — not necessary exclusivity — of the network suggest us its necessary character as the lack of organization determines that the operation could be performed only under more uncertain conditions.

On the requirement of proportionality, we must check whether the restriction’s material and geographical extension and duration do not exceed what is necessary to perform the operation.

Since in our case the restrictions linked to the efficient organization of the network are, in general, necessary throughout the life of the contract and sometimes after its extinction, such restrictions must be considered proportionate for the duration of the contractual relationship, without prejudice to the possibility of proving its lack of proportionality by the party alleging the infringement.

It seems that we may assume that if the exercise of directive power within the network — contractual or organizational — has not important effects on inter-brand competition, such as exclusionary effects or severe market sharing, and that the application of the doctrine of ancillary restraints to the networks would allow the efficient organization of the network.

VI. SOME FINAL WORDS

Business networks legal research seems to be one of the more challenging matters for Contractual Law in the next years. We hope that the group of researcher interested will increase and governments follow them for a more efficient regulation of business cooperation.

CAPÍTULO 2

Network Constitutions: a Response to the Crisis?

GUNTHER TEUBNER

INTRODUCTION

In recent years, transnational corporations (TNC) were involved in a number of scandals that shocked the global public. Ecological catastrophes, like the Exxon Valdez, Shell in Nigeria, inhuman labour conditions, child labour, the repression of union members, the disastrous price policy during the Aids crisis in South Africa, the complicity of transnational corporations in corruption and human rights violations, and with special vigour, the recent corporate abuses in the banking crisis, drastically increased the public awareness of the negative effects brought about by the transnationalization of commercial activities. In parallel, these ramifications triggered a plethora of political initiatives aimed at regulating them through binding legal norms. However, both the strong resistance of transnational corporations against national and supranational regulations as well as the difficulties to achieve effective regulation via protracted international agreements led to the failure of many of these initiatives.21 Nonetheless, one result of this shortfall is particularly noteworthy. Instead of the aspired binding state regulations, a different species of transnational non-state legal regimes spread in huge numbers around the globe — the “voluntary” codes of conduct of transnational corporations.22

Today, these codes exist in various forms, yet two basic variants predominate. On the one hand, the heavy public criticism, disseminated by the media globally, and the aggressive actions of protest movements and civil society non-governmental organizations (NGOs) force numerous transnational corporations to develop corporate codes “voluntarily”. They commit themselves to standards in the issue areas labour conditions, product quality, environmental policies, consumer protection and human rights and promise their implementation (short and imprecise: “private” codes). On the other hand, the state world establishes — through agreements under international law or through the norms of international organizations — codes of conduct for transnational corporations (again, short and imprecise: “public” codes).

How are the subjects of these private and public codes defined? It would be a misunderstanding to determine them as single formal organizations—TNCs, on the one side, and international organizations, on the other. Rather, a network revolution has taken place in both legal spaces. Extensive networks have developed between different organizations, which then facilitate the understanding of the entire configuration as the relationship between two different, mutually closed networks. On the one hand, private codes have already transcended the confines of individual companies. They have extended their validity to corporate groups and conglomerates that transcend national boundaries and encompass in some cases thousands of individual companies. Under pressure from the public and civil society organizations, their scope was even extended beyond the boundaries of corporate groups. With contractual regulations, powerful corporate groups are able to bind their suppliers and their distribution chains to their corporate codes and use the contractual mechanism also to introduce effective monitoring and sanctioning systems.23 On the other hand, interlinks in the codes of the state world can be found. Here, manifold connections between the corporate codes of the ILO, the OECD, the United Nations Organizations, and the European Union have emerged.24 Insofar the parlance of codes of corporations is misleading. This would suggest a world in which the markets are populated by isolated companies. Today’s universe of interconnected enterprises is rightly called a network society. And the adequate expression would be codes of corporate networks.

In many cases, “public” codes for corporate networks remain mere recommendations with no effects whatsoever. And the self-commitments in “private” codes are often only strategic attempts to pre-empt state regulation by the non-binding declaration of intent, or they are mere public relations strategies without involving any effective change of behaviour.25 But there are some empirical studies which deserve particular attention. They demonstrate that in some cases the corporate codes brought about real change; hence that they improved labour conditions, increased environmental protection and pushed through human rights standards.26 It is particularly noteworthy that these studies do not only document success stories; they also specify the social and legal conditions that have to be given, if the codes are meant to be successful.27 Permanent NGOs monitoring or binding contracts with civil societal certification bodies are likely to be among the most important conditions for success.

What is special about the interplay between private and the public codes for corporate networks? My thesis is: As a reaction to recent crises not only tendencies of a private juridification but also of a constitutionalization beyond the state take place. While the debate on legal pluralism, private ordering, and transnational governance concentrate on the question whether new forms of law without the state are emerging in the globalization process, I would like to focus on the question whether in reaction to the crisis stateless societal processe are also developing genuinely constitutional norms. As I have extensively argued elsewhere, this point is based on a concept of constitution that is not limited to the nation state and implies that also non-state societal orders develop autonomous constitutions under particular historical circumstances.28

I try to support this thesis with the following arguments, meant to highlight that the codes of corporate networks feature functions, structures and institutions of genuine constitutions, network constitutions:

1. To the extent that private and public codes juridify fundamental principles of a social order and establish rules for its self-restraint at the same time, they fulfil central constitutional functions for corporate networks.

2. As one among several reactions to the present crisis, a shift within these network constitutions takes place, a shift from constitutive to limitative rules.

3. With their characteristics of double reflexivity and binary meta-coding, both network codes develop genuine constitutional structures.

4. As constitutional institutions, the two codes do not form a hierarchy of public and private constitutional rules, but an ultracyclical linkage of qualitatively different networks of constitutional norms.

Thesis # 1: Constitutional Functions: Constitutive and Limitative Rules

Codes for corporate networks take part in two opposing waves of constitutionalization of the world markets. Advancing Karl Polanyi’s ideas about the transformation of modernity, one can even argue that transnational constitutionalism is part of a “double movement”.29 Also in the trajectory of corporate constitutional law, the expansion of economisation is accompanied by counter movements, which reconstruct the “protective covering of cultural institutions”.

The first constitutional movement is identified by neo-materialist critics of a “new constitutionalism” as well as by ordoliberal advocates of a world economic constitution, naturally with diametrically opposing evaluations.30 The Washington consensus of the last thirty years has pushed ahead politically with this first surge of constitutionalization of the world markets. It did not only trigger political regulation but fundamental principles of economic constitutionalism. They aimed at providing worldwide operating corporations with unlimited latitude for action, which encompassed ending governments holding shares in corporations, combating trade protectionism and freeing commercial enterprises from political regulations. In this vein, the International Monetary Fund and the World Bank have developed regime constitutions, whose guiding principle is to open up national capital markets. An integral part of these constitutionalization tendencies is the corporate governance of multinational corporate networks, whose principles encompass a high degree of corporate autonomy, the capital market-orientation of company law, and the establishing of shareholder value.31

This wave of “neo-liberal” constitutionalization is clearly characterized by its constitutive function, i.e. its focus on providing transnational corporations with a high degree of autonomy. It is fixated on the problem that the worldwide extension of corporate activities is hampered by the segmentary differentiation of the world into nation states. Constitutive rules of this kind serve for releasing the dynamic of commercial enterprises at the global level.

Thesis # 2: Externally Enforced Constitutional Self-Restraint

In the long run, however, it is not sustainable that a corporate constitutionalism restricts itself to its constitutive function in such an one-sidedly “neo-liberal” fashion. It is only a matter of time before the systemic energies released trigger disastrous consequences — alongside their indubitably productive effects. Now a fundamental readjustment of constitutional politics will be required to deal with the outburst of social conflicts. Globalized markets and corporations put — without being significantly hampered by nation state counter programs — a strain on society and the environment through the “negative effects of their own differentiation, specialization and high-performance orientation”. This is the moment when Polanyi’s “dual movement” makes its presence felt, which, as Streeck argues, identifies

“… the not just plural but inherently contradictory forces responsible for the specific dynamism of capitalist development, making it move, not linearly, but in its fits and spurts, and in cyclical waves of institutionalization and de-institutionalization”.32

In such processes of “dynamic disequilibrium”, which alternate between liberation and limitation of systemic energies, the tipping point has now been reached. After a long constitutive phase, combating the risks of unrestrained liberalisation has now become indispensable. Limitative constitutional norms are now needed rather than constitutive ones.

This is the situation after dismantling nation state regulations at a transnational level. While global function-specific communication is no longer hindered by nation-state production regimes, the constitutive constitutional politics of the Washington consensus has overriden many of the limitations that nation-states placed on the dynamics of the function systems. Unburdened by nation-state restrictions, the systems are now placed to follow, globally, a programme of maximising their partial rationality. Despite they differ in their theory assumptions, sociological analyses in the tradition of Karl Marx, Max Weber, and Niklas Luhmann all agree on the consequences of this diagnosis. Whether the laws of motion of capital, or the rationalisation of spheres of social action, or the dynamics of functional differentiation — all identify the destructive energies created by the one-sided function-orientation of a social sector. Globalisation has an accelerating effect. The dismantling of national production regimes releases destructive dynamics in the global systems; destructive dynamics in which the one-sided rationality-maximisation of one social sector collides with other social dynamics.

Now, it is imperative to readjust constitutional policy. In the second wave of constitutionalization, instead of the constitutive, the limitative function of constitutional norms is in demand. As one among many reactions to the crisis, the codes of corporate networks partake in this second wave when they restrict corporate activities in the name of public responsibility. They try to overcome the primacy of shareholder value in favour of a stakeholder-orientation as well as to realize self-restraint in the areas of labour, product quality, environment and human rights.33